Transcript of a Tele-Conference Press Briefing on "U.S. Fiscal Policies and Priorities for Long-Run Sustainability," an Occasional Paper by the IMF
January 7, 2004

United States and the IMF

IMF Staff Report on U.S. 2003 Article IV Consultation, August 2003

IMF Report on U.S. Fiscal Transparency, August 2003

Other Titles in the Occasional Paper Series




O C C A S I O N A L   P A P E R      
227
 
   
U.S. Fiscal Policies and Priorities for
Long-Run Sustainability


Martin Mühleisen and Christopher Towe, Editors

©2004 International Monetary Fund
January 7, 2004

Order information for full text in hard copy  (abstract below)

Contents
Preface
I   Overview: Returning Deficits and the Need for Fiscal Reform
  Martin Mühleisen
  The Fiscal Deficit: Back to Square One
  Costs and Consequences of Tax Cuts and Deficits
  Long-Run Insolvency of Social Security and Medicare
  The Policy Challenge
  State and Federal Fiscal Relations
  Concluding Remarks
  References
II   The Economic Impact of U.S. Budget Policies
  Roberto Cardarelli and Ayhan Kose
  Simulations of the FY2004 Budget Proposal
  Fiscal Deficits and Real Interest Rates
  International Implications of Higher U.S. Public Debt
  References
III   Social Security, Medicare, and U.S. Fiscal Prospects
  Paula De Masi, Iryna Ivaschenko, and Christopher Towe
  Fiscal Consequences of Social Security and Medicare
  The President's Social Security Reform Commission
  Medicare Reform
  Concluding Remarks
  References
IV   Long-Run U.S. Fiscal Imbalance: An Intergenerational Analysis
  Roberto Cardarelli and Christopher Towe
  Constructing Intergenerational Fiscal Accounts
  Debt Dynamics and Fiscal Sustainability
  Conclusions
  References
V   U.S. Energy Policy: The Role of Taxation
  Jim Prust and Dominique Simard
  Energy Use in the United States
  Energy Policy
  Taxation and Other Instruments to Reduce Energy Consumption
  Macroeconomic Effects of Energy Taxation
  References
VI   The Budget Enforcement Act And Options for Reform
  Michael Kell
  Background
  Assessing the BEA Rules
  Options for Reform
  Conclusion
  References
VII   Will the State and Local Budget Crisis Hinder Economic Growth?
  Iryna Ivaschenko
  State and Local Government Finances
  Recent Developments in State and Local Government Finances
  Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Adjustment
  How Much of a Drag on Growth?
  References
Boxes
  1.1. Recent U.S. Tax Initiatives
  1.2. Fiscal Transparency in the United States
  3.1. Social Security and Medicare Systems
  5.1. U.S. Energy Excise Taxes
  6.1. The Main Provisions of the BEA
Tables
  1.1. Factors Explaining Budget Turnaround
  2.1. Change in Real GDP Growth Before and After Large Fiscal Expansions
  2.2. Estimates from Large-Scale Models
  2.3. Estimates from Small-Scale Models
  2.4. Selected Studies on the Impact of Deficits on Real Interest Rates
  2.5. Correlations of G-7 Real Interest Rates (1977-2002)
  2.6. Selected Studies on the Impact of World Fiscal Variables on Real Interest Rates
  2.7. OLS Regressions of Real Interest Rates on World Fiscal Variables
  2.8. Joint GMM Estimation of National Real Interest Rates Imposing Equality of Coefficients Across Equations
  4.1. Long-Term Projections as a Share of GDP
  4.2. Indicators of Fiscal Imbalance in Alternative Economic and Policy Scenarios
  5.1. Simulated Impact of Energy Taxes on the Economy
  6.1. Adjustments to Discretionary Spending Caps
  7.1. Government Revenues, Spending, and Investment
  7.2. State and Local Governments: Composition of Receipts
  7.3. State and Local Governments: Composition of Spending and Investment, 2002
  7.4. Fiscal Impulse by Level of Government
Figures
  1.1. International Comparisons: Fiscal Balance and Net Debt
  1.2. Federal Budget Balance Adjusted for Cyclical Factors and Capital Gains Taxes
  1.3. Federal Expenditures
  1.4. Unified Budget Balance
  1.5. Revenue and Expenditure Projections
  1.6. Social Security and Medicare Outlays
  1.7. Debt Held by the Public and Social Security/Medicare Trust Funds
  1.8. Health Expenditures and Life Expectancy in OECD Countries
  2.1. Two-Year Changes in Structural Fiscal Variables
  2.2. Impact of 2003 Tax Cuts on Labor Productivity
  2.3. World Government Net Debt-to-GDP Ratio and World Real Interest Rate
  3.1. Social Security and Medicare Projections
  3.2. Budget Projections
  4.1. Tax Revenues
  4.2. Social Transfers
  4.3. Health Care Spending
  5.1. Energy Intensity of GDP: International Comparison
  5.2. Energy Intensity of GDP and Real Motor Gasoline Price
  5.3. Real Prices of Premium Unleaded Gasoline
  5.4. Prices and Taxes of Premium Unleaded Gasoline
  5.5. Carbon Dioxide Emissions per GDP
  5.6. Shares of Energy Consumption by Type of Fuel
  5.7. Net Petroleum Imports
  6.1. Federal Budget Deficit
  6.2. Federal Outlays and Revenues
  6.3. Discretionary Spending
  6.4. Mandatory Spending
  6.5. Projection Errors Due to Economic Factors
  7.1. State and Local Governments: Current Balances
  7.2. Revenues and Expenditures of State and Local Governments
  7.3. State and Local Governments: Credit Market Debt
  7.4. State and Local Governments: Budget Balances and Spreads on SLG Debt
  7.5. Dynamic Responses of the Output Gap to Fiscal Variables



I. Overview: Returning Deficits and the Need for Fiscal Reform

U.S. government finances have experienced a remarkable turnaround in recent years. Within only a few years, hard-won gains of the previous decade have been lost and, instead of budget surpluses, deficits are again projected as far as the eye can see. The deterioration has not been restricted to the federal budget but has also taken place at the state and local government levels. As a result, the U.S. general government deficit is now among the highest in the industrialized world, and public debt levels are approaching those in other major industrial countries (Figure 1.1).

Fig 1.1

Although fiscal policies have undoubtedly provided valuable support to the recovery so far, the return to large deficits raises two interrelated concerns. First, with budget projections showing large federal fiscal deficits over the next decade, the recent emphasis on cutting taxes, boosting defense and security outlays, and spurring an economic recovery may come at the eventual cost of upward pressure on interest rates, a crowding out of private investment, and an erosion of longer-term U.S. productivity growth.

Second, the evaporation of fiscal surpluses has left the budget even less well prepared to cope with the retirement of the baby boom generation, which will begin later this decade and place massive pressure on the Social Security and Medicare systems. Without the cushion provided by earlier surpluses, there is less time to address these programs' underlying insolvency before government deficits and debt begin to increase unsustainably, making more urgent the need for meaningful reform.

The remainder of this section summarizes the IMF staff's assessment of the U.S. fiscal situation,describing both the factors that have contributed to the burgeoning of the deficit and the key policy challenges posed by the impending demographic transition. It ties together subsequent sections on domestic and international implications of current budget policies; long-term prospects for Social Security and Medicare; an intergenerational analysis of long-term fiscal imbalances; the role of energy taxation; effectiveness of spending rules; and state and local government finances.

The Fiscal Deficit: Back to Square One

The 1990s were marked by significant fiscal consolidation as the economy emerged from the 1991 recession and experienced one of the longest expansions in recent history. As a result, following many years of failed attempts at exerting fiscal discipline, the federal budget—including the Social Security surplus—moved from a deficit of 4½ percent of GDP to surpluses that reached 2½ percent of GDP in FY2000 (Figure 1.2).1

Fig 1.2

Both macroeconomic developments and policy actions played an important role in achieving this correction. Strong economic growth buoyed tax revenues, and the stock market boom fueled an unprecedented increase in capital gains taxes. Estimates by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2003) suggest that cyclical factors accounted for about 4 percent of GDP of the fiscal improvement between FY1992 and FY2000, just over half the shift in the deficit ratio (see Figure 1.2).2

The balance was achieved through tax increases—including those incorporated in the 1993 Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act—and the discipline over both mandatory and discretionary spending exerted by the 1990 Budget Enforcement Act.3

Since FY2000, however, the fiscal position has eroded rapidly and, with the deficit expected to exceed 4 percent of GDP in FY2004, essentially all the gains achieved during the earlier decade have disappeared. Again, as Table 1.1 shows, the reasons for this shift include both cyclical and policy factors:4

  • The 2001 recession and the relatively weak recovery accounted for about half of the budgetary turnaround in FY2002 and FY2003. Sluggish employment growth weighed on personal income tax collections and boosted payments for income support and related programs. In addition, the bursting of the equity bubble sparked a substantial drop in capital gains tax collections, as shown in Figure 1.2, fully reversing the extraordinary increases in collections that had been achieved during the 1990s.


  • On the policy front, expenditure discipline had already relaxed considerably in the face of prolonged budget surpluses. However, the September 11 attacks and the ensuing war on terrorism, as well as efforts to stimulate the economy, prompted major increases in outlays for defense and homeland security, as well as other programs (Figure 1.3). Altogether, discretionary spending increased from 6¼ percent of GDP in FY2000 to an expected 7¼ percent of GDP in FY2003, accounting for about one-fourth of the overall fiscal turnaround.5


  • The remaining one-fourth of the turnaround resulted from tax cuts, which were enacted both to provide a countercyclical boost to the economy and bolster the longer-run supply side of the U.S. economy. The bulk of the measures was contained in the 2001 Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (EGTRRA), which introduced phased reductions in personal income tax rates and the gradual elimination of the estate tax. Relatively minor additional tax cuts were introduced in 2002, but in 2003, legislation was enacted that accelerated the previously scheduled tax cuts and also added additional elements, including a significant reduction in the tax rate applying to dividends and capital gains (Box 1.1).

Fig 1.3

Table 1.1. Factors Explaining the Budget Turnaround
(Data relate to unified budget balance including the Social Security surplus)
  Billions of U.S. dollars
Percent of Total Change
FY2002 FY2003 FY2004–08
(cumulative)
FY2002 FY2003 FY2004–08
(cumulative)

Office of Management and Budget (OMB)            
Budget balance            
  April 2001 current services baseline 283      334      2,578        . . .      . . .     . . .          
  FY2004 Mid-Session Review projection -158      -455      -1,455        . . .      . . .     . . .          
Change in budget balance -441      -789      -4,034        100      100     100          
  Of which            
  Economic and technical reestimates -284      -418      -1,782        64      53     44          
  War, homeland, and other enacted legislation -63      -193      -723        14      24     18          
Tax relief -93      -177      -1,022        21      22     25          
  2001 EGTRRA -41      -94      -761        9      12     19          
  2002 JCWAA -52      -38      19        12      5     0          
  2003 JGTRRA . . .      -45      -280        . . .      6     7          
  Pending budget proposals . . .      -1      -506        . . .      0     13          
Congressional Budget Office (CBO)            
Budget balance            
  January 2001 current services baseline 313      359      2,543        . . .      . . .     . . .          
  CBO baseline projection, August 2003 -158      -401      -1,446        . . .      . . .     . . .          
Change in budget balance -471      -760      -3,989        100      100     100          
  Of which            
  Economic and technical reestimates -306      -427      -1,871        65      56     47          
War, homeland, and other enacted legislation -55      -138      -1,185        18      18     30          
Tax relief -9      -195      -933        17      26     23          
  2001 EGTRRA 0      -93      -677        8      12     17          
  2002 JCWAA -1      -40      17        9      5     0          
  2003 JGTRRA . . .      -62      -273        . . .      8     7          

Sources: OMB, Mid-Session Review, Budget of the U.S. Government, FY2004 (July 2003); CBO, various publications; and IMF staff calculations.
Note: EGTRRA = Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act; JCWAA = Job Creation and Worker Assistance Act; JGTRRA = Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act.


Box 1.1. Recent U.S. Tax Initiatives

Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (EGTRRA) of 2001

Significant tax cuts were legislated as part of the EGTRRA in April 2001. The measures included

  • a phased reduction in the individual income tax rate over the period 2001–06, with the top rate falling from 39.6 to 35 percent and the 28, 31, and 36 percent rates falling by 3 percentage points; and the creation of a 10 percent bracket for lower incomes, with an increase in the income threshold applicable to this bracket scheduled for 2008;

  • a gradual elimination of the estate tax by 2010,with increases in exemptions and reductions in rates during 2002–09 and repeal of the tax in 2010;

  • phased increases in the child tax credit from $500 in 2001 to $1,000 in 2010;

  • marriage penalty relief, in the form of a phased increase in the standard deduction for married couples filing jointly to twice that for single taxpayers during 2005–09, and a phased increase in the
    income threshold for the 15 percent rate bracket during 2005–08;

  • alternative minimum tax (AMT) relief through an increase in exemptions by $2,000 for single taxpayers and $4,000 for joint taxpayers during 2001–04.

The 10-year cost of the measures was held to $1.35 trillion by phasing them in gradually and allowing them to expire after 2010 (that is, all tax rates were to revert to their 2001 level by the end of 2010).

Job Creation and Worker Assistance Act (JCWAA) of 2002

Additional tax initiatives were included in the economic stimulus package signed into law in March 2002. The package was estimated to cost $97 billion over FY2002–FY2003 and included

  • an allowance for businesses to take an additional first-year depreciation deduction of 30 percent on certain investments made during the three years after September 10, 2001;

  • temporal extension of the business loss-carry forward rule from two to five years;

  • tax cuts for New York City businesses damaged by the September 11 terrorist attacks.

Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA) of 2003

Further tax cuts were proposed in February 2003 as a part of the administration's FY2004 budget. The measures were estimated to cost a cumulative $1.3 trillion over FY2004–13, and included

  • an economic growth package that would bring forward to 2003 the previously scheduled reductions in marginal tax rates, increases in the child tax credit, and marriage penalty relief; eliminate the double taxation of dividends; and provide temporary tax incentives for businesses investment (at a cost of $726 billion over 10 years);

  • other tax incentives, including measures to encourage saving, charitable giving, and health care; unemployment insurance reform; and tax simplification (at a cost of $114 billion);

  • permanent extension of expiring tax provisions,including the 2001 cuts (at a cost of $588 billion).

The economic growth package was passed in the form of JGTRRA in May 2003, while other budget proposals were not legislated as of September 2003. However, JGTTRA contained only parts of the administration's growth package. Dividends were not fully excluded from personal income tax, and some measures were made subject to sunsets in order to contain the total cost to $350 billion through FY2013. The
package consisted of the following:

  • the tax rate on capital gains was lowered to 15 percent from 20 percent and was also applied to dividends. The 10 percent rate applied to capital gains of low-income households was to be reduced in phases to zero percent by 2008. These measures would expire after 2008;

  • the tax rate reductions scheduled for 2004 and 2006 were brought forward to 2003. However, the rates would still revert to pre-2001 levels after 2010. The expansion of the 10 percent income bracket scheduled for 2008 was brought forward to 2003 but is set to expire after 2007;

  • marriage penalty relief was brought forward to 2003 but set to expire after 2004;

  • the child tax credit was increased from $600 to $1,000 in 2003 and 2004, reverting to $500 in 2011;

  • AMT exemption levels were increased in 2003–05 by $4,000 for single taxpayers and $8,000 for married taxpayers filing joint returns, reverting to previous levels thereafter;

  • the annual deduction for small business investment was increased to $100,000 with expanded eligibility, and the first-year depreciation for some capital expenses was raised to 50 percent, with both measures expiring after 2004.

charts

The major tax cuts (as well as some spending measures) enacted in 2001 and 2003 have been estimated to have cost roughly $1.7 trillion over FY2002–FY2011. However, substantial debate and uncertainty have surrounded these cost estimates, largely reflecting the complicated and nontransparent manner in which the measures have been enacted. For example, some measures are only effective for a short period, while others—such as the elimination of the estate tax—are being phased in so that the fiscal cost will rise in the coming years. Moreover, all tax measures are subject to sunset clauses, which will mean that rates and deductions will—in the absence of policy action—return to pre-2001 levels in 2011 at the latest. However, it is the administration's stated intention to make the tax cuts permanent, which would leave the federal budget deficit roughly 2 percent of GDP above its baseline level by FY2013.

Costs and Consequences of Tax Cuts and Deficits

The sharp erosion in the fiscal position and the recent emphasis on tax cuts have revived a long-standing debate about the extent to which fiscal deficits crowd out private investment, and whether tax cuts, by improving economic incentives, can significantly boost the economy's supply side. The current administration has played an active role in this debate.6 It has emphasized that tax cuts would carry important longer-run supply-side benefits that could help mitigate their budgetary cost. The administration has also stressed that the federal deficit and debt-to-GDP ratios that are projected over the coming 5–10 years are "manageable" and remain well below the peak levels recorded in the 1980s and early 1990s.

There is little doubt that significant macroeconomic gains could be reaped from reforms of the U.S. tax code, with the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA, 2003) citing estimates of potential gains in the range of 2–6 percent of GDP. The tax system places a disproportionate burden on personal and corporate incomes, compared with a consumption-based tax system, discourages labor market participation and saving, and is, hence, economically less efficient. The administration's 2003 proposals were viewed as a significant move toward a consumption-based tax system, because the initial package of measures announced in February would have lowered marginal income tax rates, eliminated the double taxation of dividends, and significantly expanded the extent to which income earned on saving would have been tax free.

Moreover, tax reform that simplified the system could also yield significant gains, given that the multitude of tax deductions and exemptions have imposed considerable administrative and other costs. As noted in CEA (2003), taxpayers are required to spend roughly 3 billion hours a year dealing with federal tax matters, and overall compliance costs are estimated at around 10 percent of total federal tax revenues.It remains an open question whether the tax cuts adopted since early 2001 will have significant supply-side benefits:

Although the cuts in income tax rates will—at the margin—improve incentives to work, the labor participation rate is already high, and empirical studies do not suggest that it is highly tax elastic (Angrist, 1991; Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir, 1998).7

  • Moreover, in their final form, the tax measures appear to have taken only modest steps toward shifting the tax burden from income to consumption. Although tax rates on dividends and capital gains were lowered, the administration was not successful in eliminating the double taxation of corporate income or expanding the deductibility of saving from income.
  • Moreover, there is considerable academic debate about the likely magnitude of any supply-side benefits from reducing taxes on dividends. For example, it has recently been argued that the effect on capital spending would be minimal, especially because increased dividend payouts could reduce funds available for new capital spending (e.g., Gale and Orszag, 2003).
  • The measures also did little to address the complexity of the U.S. tax system. A number of the originally proposed simplifications did not pass, including on tax-preferred savings instruments. Indeed, in many respects the legislation appeared to have only added to the complexity of the system, for example, by using phase-ins and sunsets to obscure the true budget cost and expanding the number of tax preferences.

The modest efficiency gains that might arise from the recent tax cuts will also have to be weighed against the effects of a prolonged period of fiscal weakness. As shown in Figure 1.4, the FY2004 budget is expected to result in deficits well into the next decade—a substantial deterioration compared with the January 2002 current services baseline, which saw a return to budgetary surpluses around 2007.Although the deficit ratio is expected to narrow somewhat as the economy recovers in coming years, there are important reasons to worry that these projections may still prove optimistic (Figure 1.5). The strict limits on discretionary spending that have been assumed may be difficult to sustain, especially because of pressures to increase outlays on defense and homeland security, as yet undefined supporting policies for ensuring that limits on other discretionary programs are adhered to, and reduced pressure to maintain spending discipline as a result of the expiration of the Budget Enforcement Act (BEA).8 Also, there are significant uncertainties about tax revenue projections. Notably, the official budget projections do not take into account the costs of reforming the Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT), and are predicated on the assumption that the recent (and still not fully understood) sharp drop in personal tax revenue will be largely reversed.9 With U.S. fiscal deficits expected to persist into the foreseeable future, will any supply-side benefits be outweighed by the effect of weaker public saving on interest rates and investment? The Council of Economic Advisers (2003) argued strongly that these potential offsetting effects would be minimal. However, the estimates surveyed in Section II generally suggest that the short-term stimulus stemming from the FY2004 budget proposals is likely to wane in several years, with higher deficits beginning to crowd out private investment and dampen output thereafter. In one simulation, for example, the tax cuts would eventually lower U.S. productivity—in terms of labor output per hour—by ½ percent in the long run.

Figs 4.4. & 4.5

Global Issues

Although U.S. fiscal policy has undoubtedly provided valuable support to the global economy in recent years, large U.S. fiscal deficits also pose significant risks for the rest of the world. Simulations reported in Section II suggest that a 15 percentage point increase in the U.S. public debt ratio projected over the next decade would eventually raise real interest rates in industrial countries by an average of ½–1 percentage point. Higher borrowing costs abroad would mean that the adverse effects of U.S. fiscal deficits would spill over into global investment and output.

Moreover, against the background of a record-high U.S. current account deficit and a ballooning U.S. net foreign liability position, the emergence of twin fiscal and current account deficits has given rise to renewed concern. The United States is on course to increase its net external liabilities to around 40 percent of GDP within the next few years—an unprecedented level of external debt for a large industrial country (IMF, 2003b). This trend is likely to continue to put pressure on the U.S. dollar, particularly because the current account deficit increasingly reflects low saving rather than high investment.

Although the dollar's adjustment could occur gradually over an extended period, the possible global risks of a disorderly exchange rate adjustment, especially to financial markets, cannot be ignored. Episodes of rapid dollar adjustments failed to inflict significant damage in the past, but with U.S. net external debt at record levels, an abrupt weakening of investor sentiments vis-à-vis the dollar could possibly lead to adverse consequences both domestically and abroad.10

Long-Run Insolvency of Social Security and Medicare

From a long-term perspective, higher U.S. fiscal deficits are especially worrisome because of the precarious financial position of the Social Security and Medicare systems. Although U.S. demographics compare relatively favorably with most other industrialized nations (see discussion in Section III), both systems are projected to run sizable deficits about a decade from now when the baby boom generation enters its peak retirement years, and accumulated surpluses are exhausted 10–20 years thereafter.

The Social Security system is under pressure as a result of both the declining fertility rate—which (unlike in many other countries) is somewhat offset by higher immigration—and increases in longevity. As a result, the dependency ratio—the ratio of retirees to the working-age population—is projected to rise from 20 percent at present to around 40 percent by the middle of the century. This implies that payroll tax revenues will decline while social security spending is expected to roughly double as a proportion of GDP (Figure 1.6). The financial position of the Medicare and Medicaid systems is considerably worse, given the rapid growth of health care costs and the modest share of benefits that is covered by individual contributions. Medicare expenditures are projected to grow almost threefold relative to GDP over the next five decades, and considerable increases are also likely in the case of Medicaid.11

The projected sharp increase in expenditures, relative to contributions, and the rapid increase in health care costs mean that the Social Security and Medicare systems are highly under funded. Unless steps are taken to adjust contribution rates and benefits, the programs will fall into deficit in the next two decades and have to be supported by growing transfers out of the federal general fund. IMF staff simulations of the rapid increase of federal debt that would result—which are similar to those presented by the CBO and the administration's FY2004 budget—are shown in Figure 1.7.

Figs 1.6 & 1.7

Official estimates place the net present value of the programs' unfunded actuarial liability at around 160 percent of current GDP, if measured over a 75-year horizon.12 But even these estimates understate the financial problems facing these programs because, in the absence of policy action, the programs will be running large cash flow deficits past this projection horizon. Moreover, closing the fiscal gap can be accomplished through a variety of policy measures (e.g., tax hikes, spending cuts, and so on) and at varying speed, both of which have different implications that are not captured by typical actuarial measures.

These considerations have led to a renewed emphasis on estimates of the fiscal gap, which take into account longer horizons and the intergenerational transfers that are involved. Section IV presents estimates of the U.S. fiscal imbalance using an intergenerational accounting framework that encompasses the entire federal fiscal system over an infinite horizon. The results suggest that the fiscal imbalance is as high as $47 trillion, nearly 500 percent of current GDP, and that closing this fiscal gap would require an immediate and permanent 60 percent hike in the federal income tax yield, or a 50 percent cut in Social Security and Medicare benefits. The analysis also illustrates that this gap is associated with a severe intergenerational imbalance, with the burden on future generations increasing further if corrective measures are delayed.

The Policy Challenge

To restore a sustainable position, U.S. fiscal policy must refocus on two key objectives. The first is to adopt a clear and credible policy framework to achieve a balanced budget (excluding the Social Security surplus) over the cycle. The second is to pursue the reforms needed to place the Social Security and Medicare systems on a sound financial footing.

Restoring Budget Balance

Balancing the budget, excluding Social Security, has been an underlying goal of U.S. fiscal policy since at least 1985, when this objective was enshrined in the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings legislation. It is also an objective that the current administration has endorsed in the past—for example, the FY2002 budget was committed to saving the entire Social Security surplus, allowing almost all outstanding federal debt to be repaid over 10 years. The focus on balanced budgets is grounded in the realization that today's Social Security surpluses represent an accumulation of contributions by program participants that need to be saved to fund future retirement benefits.

With the approaching retirement of the baby boom generation, reestablishing a balanced U.S. federal deficit is becoming increasingly urgent. Achieving this objective over a 5–10-year period would leave the government debt ratio more than 10 percent of GDP lower in 2013 than at present and provide much-needed room for designing and implementing the reform of entitlement programs in advance of the demographic shock (see Figure 1.7 for an illustration). Returning to a balanced budget would also help ensure that the eventual adjustment of the U.S. current account deficit is orderly and rests on stronger national saving rather than weaker U.S. investment and growth.13

How large a fiscal adjustment would be needed to meet this objective? The CBO's August 2003 baseline suggests that the effort would need to be significant. For example, assuming that the recent tax cuts are made permanent, amendments to the Medicare system are implemented, and steps are taken to address the reform of the Alternative Minimum Tax system, the unified budget deficit would fall to around 1½ percent of GDP in 2013. This measure still includes the surplus of the Social Security Trust Fund, however, which is classified as an "off-budget" item in the U.S. fiscal accounts. Once this surplus is excluded, the budget deficit, and the measures needed for balance, would be over 3 percent of GDP.14 However, these estimates assume that extremely strict limits on discretionary spending—which keeps spending constant in real terms—are maintained for 10 years, and even larger shortfalls can be envisaged.

Given the magnitude of this adjustment, it would seem likely that both revenue measures and sustained spending restraints would need to be considered. On the revenue side, allowing the tax cuts to expire would yield around 2 percent of GDP, including the associated interest saving, but any revenue effort would also need to look for opportunities to expand the tax base. Recent CBO publications have illustrated that substantial revenues could be derived from reducing corporate and personal income tax preferences—including corporate tax shelters and mortgage interest deductibility. Section V suggests that energy taxes, which are comparatively light in the United States, could help meet the administration's environmental objectives while also providing substantial support for fiscal consolidation.

These measures would have to go hand-in-hand with a tightening of expenditure discipline, which weakened significantly with the emergence of surpluses in the late 1990s. In recent years, geopolitical considerations and the war on terrorism have compounded spending pressures, but these and other spending priorities will need to be weighed carefully if the adjustment burden is not to fall more heavily on the revenue side.

To support efforts to rein in public spending, greater weight could be given to reintroducing and strengthening the budget rules contained in the Budget Enforcement Act (BEA), which expired in October 2002. The international and U.S. experience is that fiscal adjustment tends to be more effective if it is based on formal rules embedded in a fiscal policy framework with clearly defined medium- and long-term objectives, similar to the fiscal responsibility legislation adopted by a number of industrial countries. Such a framework—and the political consensus that would surround it—could help provide policy-makers with an appropriate basis for facing the difficult trade-offs in the period ahead.

A similar conclusion has been reached by a recent IMF report on U.S. fiscal transparency, which generally praised the high degree of transparency in the United States but noted a lack of clarity in the longer-term direction of its fiscal policy (Box 1.2). Fiscal responsibility legislation could also help guard against using accounting devices that obscure the true cost of measures and lead to loss of credibility, as appears to have been the case in recent years. Section VI shows that the caps on discretionary outlays and pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) requirements contained in the BEA strongly contributed to the successful fiscal consolidation in the United States during the 1990s. Although the BEA's constraints were increasingly circumvented just prior to its expiration, Section VI suggests a range of options for further strengthening these types of budget rules.

Box 1.2. Fiscal Transparency in the United States

During November 2002–February 2003, a staff team conducted a review of fiscal transparency in the United States in relation to the IMF's Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency (IMF, 2003a). The principal conclusions of that review are as follows:

  • The United States is fully compliant with most elements of the Fund's Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency and sets best practice standards in many areas. The U.S. Constitution provides a strong and well-tested framework that clearly defines the roles of the executive and legislative branches in fiscal management. The Congress plays a central role in shaping the budget, which ensures a highly open process. State and local governments also have clearly defined fiscal responsibilities, operating independently from the federal government, and are subject to market discipline. Budget documentation is easily accessible to the public, timely, comprehensive, and reliable, and it excels in its scope and quality of analysis.

  • Nevertheless, there remains a lack of clarity about the longer-term direction of fiscal policy. This partly reflects the sheer size of the federal government and the complexity of the congressional budget process. Major efforts have been made over the past three decades to put in place a legal framework to strengthen this aspect of the budget process. However, with the expiration of the Budget Enforcement Act (BEA), the failure of Congress to pass a budget resolution for FY2003, and the recent uncertainty regarding the permanence of tax cuts and the costs of the war in Iraq, budget decisions do not seem presently guided by clear medium- and long-term fiscal policy objectives.

  • Budget responsibility legislation to replace the BEA could help provide a basis for a more systematic incorporation of longer-term considerations into the budget process. Building on existing budget requirements and practices, such a budget framework could require the specification and justification of medium-term fiscal targets as part of the President's budget; a budget report on long-term fiscal policy; discretionary spending caps and pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) requirements for mandatory spending and revenue; and clearer procedures for specifying and disclosing key budget assumptions (e.g., with respect to expiring legislation).

  • Fiscal transparency could be strengthened in a number of additional ways: reporting an internationally comparable measure of the budget balance to supplement the unified budget presentation; providing an overview of state and local government finances as part of the federal budget presentation; annually assessing the costs and risks associated with the quasi-fiscal activities; including a comprehensive statement on fiscal risks in budget documents; reconsidering the legal basis for tax expenditure reporting; ensuring that audit reports of agencies by the General Accounting Office (GAO) are followed up, possibly by a standing public accounts committee that reports to Congress; increasing the emphasis on program performance; and paying greater attention to the full cost of providing government services.

Reforming Entitlement Programs

Although the impact of population aging will not be felt fully until well into the next decade, and public debt ratios are not expected to rise before 2020, the long lead times required in reforming pension and health insurance programs suggest that policy actions need to be taken well in advance. For example, the 1983 reform of the Social Security system raised the normal retirement age from 65 to 67, but to allow workers to adjust their saving and retirement plans, the increase was scheduled to be phased in over a 25-year period, beginning only in 2002.

At this stage, relatively modest changes would still appear to be sufficient to close projected pension shortfalls. For example, an immediate 2 percentage point hike in the Social Security payroll tax could be sufficient to close the system's 75-year actuarial liability. However, payroll taxes in the United States are already high and further increases would tend to be regressive and could adversely affect incentives to hire labor. Other options include measures to stem the growth of benefits, including by indexing the calculation of pension benefits to the consumer price index (CPI) rather than wages, further increasing the normal retirement age, or reducing the benefits for early retirement. In general, however, the longer such decisions are delayed, the larger and more painful the required adjustments will be.

Privatizing Social Security could, in principle, provide a framework for addressing the system's unfunded liability, but would still require either cuts in benefits or hikes in premiums, as well as an explicit recognition of the liabilities that the system has already accrued. Moreover, the higher returns that might be earned from personal retirement accounts would have to be weighed against the increased exposure of retirement savings to market fluctuations, which would likely require the government to still provide a minimum safety net for retirees. Questions have also been raised about the administrative costs that would have to be borne in managing small accounts, and the challenge of designing a system that discourages workers from withdrawing excessive amounts at retirement and imposing a burden on the rest of the system.

Medicare reform is even more critical. The Medicare trust fund begins to run into deficit in 2016, and the unfunded actuarial liability (in net present value terms) has been estimated at 130 percent of current GDP. This raises the question of whether it would have been prudent to defer an extension of benefits, including to cover prescription drugs, until credible measures to address the system's longer-term financial problems are established. Indeed, the broader weakness of the U.S. health care system—which has left health care spending the highest among OECD countries (relative to GDP), without a commensurately high ranking in public health indicators (see Figure 1.8)—suggests that more sweeping reforms of the system may be needed.

Fig 1.8

State and Federal Fiscal Relations

A review of the U.S. fiscal situation would be incomplete without considering the relatively sharp deterioration of state and local government finances in recent years. In aggregate, this sector accounts for close to half of general government spending, raising concern that expenditure cutbacks on the state and local levels could offset some of the stimulus provided by the federal government. This issue is addressed in Section VII, which reviews the principal causes of the state and local fiscal crisis and attempts to quantify its macroeconomic implications. Rising deficits have been caused both by shrinking corporate and personal income tax revenues and by sharp increases in cyclical and health-related spending—in part reflecting tax cuts and more generous benefit levels granted during the boom years of the 1990s. With budget reserves being increasingly eroded, further adjustment measures will be needed. However, the aggregate size of local and state government cutbacks is estimated to be only a small fraction of the overall stimulus provided by the federal government, and their macroeconomic impact is likely to remain small.

Concluding Remarks

Meaningful reforms of entitlement programs such as Social Security and Medicare tend to require long lead times, given their impact on intergenerational income distribution and politically controversial nature. To reach broad-based agreement on such reforms, fiscal resources are often required to smooth the transition and ensure that reform measures can be implemented over a politically acceptable time horizon. Only a few years ago, the conditions for movement on these fronts seemed to be in place in the United States, with the demographic shock still half a generation away and government debt set to be all but eliminated within a decade. Since then, however, a combination of cyclical, geopolitical, and policy factors have erased a decade's worth of fiscal consolidation, just a short time before the retirement of the baby boom generation begins.

The discussion in this and subsequent sections suggests that the U.S. fiscal problem is still manageable, and there remains a window of opportunity for reform. However, the experience of recent decades has shown that fiscal consolidation is difficult to achieve and perhaps even more difficult to hold on to. Therefore, the room for maneuver is narrowing quickly.

References

Angrist, J., 1991, "Grouped-Data Estimation and Testing in Simple Labor-Supply Models," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 47, No. 2/3, pp. 243–66.

Blundell, R., A. Duncan, and C. Meghir, 1998, "Estimating Labor Supply Responses Using Tax Reforms," Econometrica, Vol. 66, No. 4, pp. 827–62.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO), 2003, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2004–2013 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office).

Council of Economic Advisers (CEA), 2003, Economic Report of the President, February 2003 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office).

Gale, W.G., and P.R. Orszag, 2003, "The Administration's Proposal to Cut Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes," Tax Notes (Washington: Urban Institute, Brookings Institution), January. Available via Internet: www.taxpolicycenter.org/commentary/taxnotes.cfm.

Gross, D.B., and N.S. Souleles, 2001, "Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data," NBER Working Paper No. 8314 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

Gruber, J., and E. Saez, 2000, "The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications," NBER Working Paper No. 7512 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

International Monetary Fund, 2003a, United States: Report on the Observance of Standards and Codes—Fiscal Transparency Module, IMF Staff Country Report No. 03/243 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

———, 2003b, World Economic Outlook, September 2003: Public Debt in Emerging Markets (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Leidy, M., 1998, "A Postmortem on the Achievement of Federal Fiscal Balance," in United States: Selected Issues, IMF Staff Country Report No. 98/105 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Office of Management and Budget (OMB), 2003a, Budget of the U.S. Government, Fiscal Year 2004 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office).

——— , 2003b, Mid-Session Review, Budget of the U.S. Government, FY2004 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office), July.


1The U.S. fiscal year runs from October through September.
2The calculation of cyclical factors has been complicated by the sharp increase in capital gains tax revenues during the stock market boom of the 1990s. The CBO does not treat these revenues as a cyclical factor, but they clearly need to be excluded for identifying policy-related factors. Hence, Figure 1.2 includes a cyclically adjusted balance that has been corrected for the deviation of capital gains tax revenues from their historical average.
3Some studies have suggested a lesser contribution from cyclical factors, partly reflecting difficulties in distinguishing cyclical effects from structural shifts in the economy. For example, Leidy (1998) found that only about 20–25 percent of the fiscal improvement between FY1992 and FY1997 was caused by the cycle. He estimated that roughly half the turnaround was accounted for by tax measures and another one-fourth by reductions in discretionary spending relative to GDP.
4Both the Office of Management and Budget and the CBO regularly present a decomposition of changes in the budget balance into cyclical and other factors.
5Discretionary spending is controlled by annual appropriations acts. Mandatory spending is provided by permanent law and does not require annual appropriations to ensure the continuation of spending.
6See, for example, the discussion in OMB (2003a).
7At the same time, the short-term demand effect of the tax cuts is likely to have been limited by the fact that higher-income households tend to derive most of the income gains from tax reform (Gruber and Saez, 2000) but generally have a lower marginal propensity to consume than lower-income households (e.g., Gross and Souleles, 2001).
8For example, the administration's $87 billion supplemental to cover the costs of ongoing military operations and reconstruction in Afghanistan and Iraq was about twice the size expected at the time the staff projections underlying Figure 1.5 were made.
9The AMT is a parallel income tax system with fewer exemptions, deductions, and rates than the regular income tax (e.g., personal exemptions and the standard deduction are not allowed under the AMT). It was enacted to limit the extent to which high-income taxpayers can reduce their tax liability by using preferences in the regular tax code. Due to increases in nominal income, the number of tax returns subject to the AMT is projected to increase from 4 million in 2004 to 33 million in 2010.
10In a March 2003 speech, delivered at a Bank of France symposium, Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan remarked on the U.S. current account deficit: "There are limits to the accumulation of net claims against an economy that persistent current account deficits imply. The cost of servicing such claims adds to the current account deficit and, under certain circumstances, can be destabilizing."
11Cost increases for Medicaid are less strongly driven by demographic developments, since benefits are provided to all low-income households independent of age.
12OMB, 2003a, Chapter 3. This estimate assumes that current assets of the Social Security Trust Fund will be used to cover future pension benefits.
13Federal Reserve Chairman Greenspan also made this point in his February 2002 speech to the National Summit on Retirement Savings.
14The Social Security surplus reflects an accumulation of assets that is—in principle—matched by future obligations to retirees. For this reason, U.S. policymakers and other analysts have often focused on measures of the fiscal balance that exclude the Social Security surplus.