Share This
June 2007 Cover Art

Search Finance & Development


Advanced Search
About F&D

Subscribe

Back Issues

Write Us

Copyright Information

Free Email Notification

Receive emails when we post new items of interest to you.

Subscribe or Modify your profile

Finance & Development
A quarterly magazine of the IMF
June 2007, Volume 44, Number 2


A Government's Net Worth
Bob Traa and Alina Carare

A new tool in surveillance, the public sector balance sheet, can help diagnose vulnerabilities that are not immediately visible in the budget


With the economic crises of the 1990s, economists were reminded that they could no longer rely solely on a country's so-called flow variables (among them revenues, expenditures, imports, exports, and borrowing) as a guide to economic vulnerabilities. Financial health turns out to be more complicated than the relationship between income and outgo—the flow analysis of macroeconomics that has been the workhorse of fiscal policy since John Maynard Keynes provided a structure to analyze its impact on growth, inflation, and employment. Studying the accumulated stocks of assets and liabilities of a country (public, private, and external), and mismatches among them, can be a supplemental guide to uncover distress.

What holds for the country holds for the public sector as well. Many vulnerabilities do not show up in the budget, but become apparent when a public sector balance sheet reflecting all assets and liabilities is constructed. Analyzing the government's net worth and what causes it to change can lead to understanding the need for better policies. For example:

  • Ecuador's oil production contributes large revenues to the budget, but is gradually depleting the state-owned oil reserves (assets). Its revenue flows may look healthy even as its balance sheet (a stock concept) suggests that net worth is declining.
  • When the present value of future social security claims is recognized as a liability in the balance sheet, the fiscal position in Germany and Switzerland, among other advanced countries, suddenly looks more challenging.

Shocks to stock variables can ruin countries. In many recent financial crises—Korea, Thailand, Indonesia, Argentina, Uruguay, and Ecuador—the root cause was not a simple flow imbalance (for example, a public or private sector deficit), but rather a sudden loss of investor confidence that affected prices of financial assets or an exchange rate crisis that led to a collapse in net worth as debt denominated in foreign currency increased while there were losses on assets. Private or public entities do not succumb easily to pressures from a budget deficit, even when it continues for a few years, because flow imbalances, such as deficits, can be relatively quickly corrected once the political will to do so materializes. But correcting a stock imbalance can require efforts that stretch a decade.

In recent years, the IMF has increasingly incorporated analysis of stock variables in its monitoring of countries' economies and the global economy—what is known as the balance sheet approach in surveillance (Allen and others, 2002 and 2007; Rosenberg and others, 2005). This methodology uses linkages within and between the balance sheets of the private and public sectors and the external position of the economy to reveal stress affecting different sectors, and how valuation changes or other shocks can cause an abrupt unwinding of these imbalances. It often includes a partial balance sheet for the public sector, focusing on financial assets and liabilities (excluding nonfinancial or intertemporal information). This goes beyond the more narrowly defined public debt but is incomplete because it leaves out much vital information. An approach that focuses on the net worth of the public sector by itself is gradually finding its way into surveillance.

Indeed, the IMF Statistics Department and the Fiscal Affairs Department presented a blueprint for linking public sector flow accounts (budget reporting) and stock accounts (balance sheet reporting) in the Government Finance Statistics Manual (IMF, 2001). It reflects government activities in a statement of the operations of government covering transactions in revenues, expense, the net acquisition of nonfinancial assets, and financing; a gross cash flow statement; and a balance sheet that explains changes in the stock positions in assets and liabilities at the beginning and the end of the accounting period by transactions in revenues and expense that affect net worth and other economic flows, including valuation and volume changes (IMF, 2005; Da Costa and Juan- Ramon, 2006). Countries are implementing these guidelines but because data requirements are demanding, progress has been gradual. Meanwhile, the staff has been exploring available balance sheet material to see if it can shed light on risks and broader sustainability issues in fiscal analysis.

Totting up assets and liabilities

The basic concept of a public sector balance sheet is clear: add up all financial and nonfinancial assets accumulated over the years on one side, and all debt and other liabilities on the other—the difference is the public sector net worth (see Table 1). By recording both assets (nonfinancial and financial) and liabilities, the balance sheet enables analysts to assess the impact of fiscal policies on net worth and to evaluate trends in net worth over time as a basis for determining the sustainability of fiscal policies.


Table 1
What a public sector balance sheet shows

It totals assets and liabilities to find a government's net worth.

Conceptual public sector balance sheet
(percent of GDP)
Assets
120
Financial assets
30
   Cash
5
   Deposits
25
Nonfinancial assets
90
   Net capital stock
55
   Public enterprises
35
Liabilities
120
Gross debt
70
Other liabilities1
35
Net worth
15

1Could include contingent and/or implicit liabilities.

But reality is not that straightforward. Many governments do not know what assets they have acquired over the years, what they owe, or who holds title (for instance with contingent or certain future liabilities). Moreover, the prices at which assets and liabilities need to be entered into the balance sheet (market or nominal book values) make an important difference.

Examples of how even a simple stand-alone balance sheet can suggest vulnerabilities in fiscal analysis include:

Exchange rates. Many private and public sectors carry some foreign currency–denominated or indexed debt on their balance sheet, which can accumulate to a point where even a small exchange rate change can become costly. This could affect the government finances in two ways. First, the exchange rate change can directly increase the cost of the public debt on the government's books. Second, it can force the government to absorb private sector debts if bankruptcies among households and businesses with debts in foreign currencies push lenders such as banks into insolvency. To prevent further damage, the public sector sometimes has no choice but to socialize part of the costs of the private defaulted debt through deposit insurance or bailouts. None of the risks from currency mismatches can be observed directly in flow accounts and, without a comprehensive balance sheet analysis, they tend to go undetected for too long. For example, vulnerability to exchange rate risks was important in Argentina and Uruguay leading up to the crises in the early 2000s.

Public enterprises. Voters generally know about the public debt but are less aware of their ownership in and the performance of state assets and enterprises. Take Uruguay in 2001. State enterprises were returning relatively little to the taxpayers and, as a group, their net worth was lagging, especially the state banks. At the same time, Uruguay was rapidly accumulating debt, much of it in foreign currency. Preliminary staff calculations suggested that the value of the enterprises was still enough until 2000 or so that they could have been sold and the proceeds used to extinguish or sharply reduce the debt, in turn reducing or ending the foreign currency mismatch on the public balance sheet (see Table 2). Uruguay had already engaged in a substantial discussion about whether to divest the enterprises but in the end opted against it, perhaps because the public did not fully realize that the enterprises were not generating a sufficient return. In contrast, Australia has shown that it helps to garner political support for better management or divestment if the authorities inform the public about their asset holdings and systematically disclose their return.


Table 2
Accounting for public firms

A balance sheet would have enhanced awareness of the trade-off between low-yielding public firms and growing high-interest debt.

Uruguay—Preliminary public sector balance sheet
(million dollars)
 
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Assets
11,497
11,488
11,259
11,987
12,023
10,887
   Central bank net worth
1
-29
-140
-13
-6
-123
   Public enterprises
6,160
6,362
6,468
6,860
6,862
5,662
   Capital, net
4,925
4,704
4,520
4,730
4,756
4,937
   Other, net
411
411
411
410
411
411
Liabilities
11,497
11,488
11,259
11,987
12,023
10,887
   Debt
5,199
5,441
5,779
6,368
6,621
7,232
   Net worth
6,298
6,007
5,480
5,619
5,402
3,655

Source: IMF Country Report No. 01/185, October 2001.

Resource depletion. For some countries, oil reserves are the most important asset on the public sector balance sheet, and they feel well-off if they can sell the oil for use in (current) spending. But from a balance sheet perspective, the country is using a nonrenewable resource and consuming its assets. The sovereign's net worth is declining. This goes undetected when no public sector balance sheet is produced (see Table 3). The IMF and Ecuador discussed resource depletion in 2003, and the IMF staff recommended placing oil receipts in the financing statement (instead of the budget) and focusing policies on developing the non-oil economy for a soft landing when the oil runs out. There are cases where countries have developed wealth management funds with the proceeds from oil or other commodities—to smooth out over time the consumption of these important state assets—including Norway, Russia, and Chile (copper).


Table 3
Accounting for oil use and the environment

It is hard to value ecological assets, but the IMF tried to do so in Ecuador, plus calculated the declining value of oil and gas reserves.

Ecuador—Public sector balance sheet
(million dollars)
 
1970
1980
1990
2000
Prel. 2002
Assets
7,818
258,724
131,082
140,400
116,489
   Deposits
54
494
359
1,228
1,282
   Central bank net worth
35
327
237
1,343
1,037
   Public enterprises
586
5,404
3,927
4,430
5,389
   Capital stock, net
606
3,777
7,445
11,204
12,819
   Oil and gas reserves
6,134
245,000
116,410
118,093
89,694
   Biodiversity and
      carbon capture
403
3,722
2,704
4,102
6,268
Liabilities
7,818
258,724
131,082
140,400
116,489
   Shortfalls in
      insurance funds
395
3,645
2,648
4,017
6,138
   Debt
536
5,132
8,554
13,227
13,730
   Arrears
0
0
3,033
1,331
789
   Net worth
6,860
249,947
116,847
121,825
95,832
   With oil and gas at
      2001 prices
139,303
133,486
114,280
96,374
94,139

Source: IMF Country Report No. 03/91, April 2003.

The environment. For years, it seemed that pollution could be absorbed by the environment without difficulty, but pollution pressure has grown so large that symptoms of distress are surfacing. One problem is that clean air and water, or diffuse concepts such as biodiversity, have no well-defined price and are difficult to value in economic modeling. But if a good is a public good with social benefits, it makes sense to try to value it on the public sector balance sheet, and for it to be managed with either appropriate regulation or revenue-generating licensing. Slowly, the value of "goods" such as CO2 capture and biodiversity, as well as "bads" such as carbon emissions, is being priced in market systems to become tradable goods that yield cash flow.

Take Ecuador, which has one of the world's richest natural environments. In 2002–03, when IMF staff met with the authorities for the annual country consultation, they agreed to include environmental data in the public sector balance sheet (see Table 3). Although the Fund has no standard for environmental accounting, the staff consulted experts in Ecuador who had used formulas from the Kyoto Treaty to value biodiversity and the capacity of forests to act as carbon sinks to calculate a notional economic value for ecological wealth in their country. Environmental trade-offs at that time were particularly acute, because the country had issued permits for a new oil pipeline that opened the interior Amazon rain forest and carried the oil through ecologically sensitive areas. The idea of the exercise was not to provide a new cost-benefit analysis of the oil pipeline project but rather to encourage a discussion on trade-offs that need to be made when pitting economic growth against environmental sustainability.

Intertemporal accounting and fiscal sustainability. Fiscal sustainability is often analyzed in terms of how well debt can be managed. But debt is only one of the liabilities on the public sector balance sheet. It is difficult to see the so-called intertemporal liabilities—including the future unfunded social security claims that are now attracting attention as baby boomers near retirement.

In recent talks with Germany and Switzerland, the IMF staff has developed preliminary intertemporal public sector balance sheets that include the net present value of future unfunded liabilities (see Table 4). These liabilities reflect prospective fiscal deficits, essentially driven by aging costs in the social security system (such as pensions, health care, and long-term care) under current policies (a baseline scenario) over a rolling 50-year horizon. These liabilities are sometimes much larger than the existing debt, and including them in the balance sheet turns public sector net worth from positive to negative.


Table 4
When costs rise in the future

After the present value of future welfare liabilities such as social security are taken into account, Germany's
and Switzerland's positive net worth disappears.

Germany—Preliminary public sector balance sheet
(percent of GDP)
 
2003
2004
2005
20061
Financial net worth
-46
-49
-51
-53
   Gross debt
-63
-65
-66
-68
   Other
17
16
15
15
Nonfinancial net worth
56
55
55
54
   Net capital stock
51
50
50
49
   Other
5
5
5
5
Current net worth
10
6
4
1
   NPV of implicit future
      liabilities
-191
-150
-114
-30
Intertemporal net worth
-181
-145
-111
-28

Source: IMF Country Report No. 06/438.
1Assumes that the fiscal balance will be zero in 2010; and that incremental aging costs are 4 percent of GDP by 2050.

Switzerland—Preliminary public sector balance sheet
(percent of GDP)
 
2003
2004
2005
20061
Financial net worth
-23
-24
-22
-21
   Gross debt
-54
-53
-52
-48
   Other
31
29
30
27
Nonfinancial net worth
72
71
73
70
   Net capital stock
56
55
55
53
   Other
16
16
18
17
Current net worth
49
47
51
49
   NPV of implicit future
      liabilities
-153
-152
-152
-103
Intertemporal net worth
-104
-105
-101
-54

Source: Forthcoming IMF Country Report 2007.
1Assumes that incremental aging costs are 6.3 percent of GDP by 2050.

At present, international convention, including IMF methodology, does not consider unfunded pensions a government liability, but this interpretation is likely to change. Standard and Poor's rating agency has warned that with unchanged policies, the Group of Seven industrial countries (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States) could lose their investment credit rating over the next two decades based on the deleterious effects on the public finances of these emerging aging costs (Kraemer, Chambers, and Merino, 2005). It is no surprise, therefore, that Germany, Switzerland, and many other countries are engaging in adjustment and structural reforms to prepare their economies for the coming wave of retirements and other aging costs.

Moreover, intertemporal public sector balance sheets can provide valuable information that can point out the benefits of stronger economic policies. Structural reforms, for example, are notoriously difficult to approve and implement because in the short run the public does not see clearly the (flow) benefits. Instead, an intertemporal approach can allow voters to better understand the trade-off between doing something now or waiting. Running different scenarios through the balance sheet can show that doing nothing often leads to the need for more severe action later on, because the country is then confronted with a further-deteriorated public sector net worth. Conversely, if reforms are implemented that improve long-run growth and reduce aging costs, the intertemporal position of the state will strengthen, and the public can see that this bolsters the sustainability of the welfare state.

Indeed, in 2003–04, Germany initiated important reforms to reduce future aging costs. Then in 2006–07, the coalition government took further important measures (including a hike in the value-added tax) to strengthen the fiscal balance. Similarly, Switzerland has been strengthening its underlying fiscal accounts with the help of the debt brake fiscal rule, and has also made important progress with structural reforms that, in the view of the IMF, have improved potential output growth. The benefits from these policies are again visible in stronger intertemporal balance sheets in Germany and Switzerland.

Further steps

More work is needed to implement public sector balance sheets and learn how to integrate stock analysis with traditional macroeconomic flow analysis. The first step might be to complete as much as possible a first rendering of the public sector balance sheet in all countries at book value (the cost of acquisition less depreciation). The next step could be to value selected assets and liabilities at market prices, as appropriate; many governments already report their registered debt on a mark-to-market basis. An even more sophisticated approach would be to prepare "stochastic balance sheets." These recognize that standard balance sheets are snapshots of assets and liabilities at a point in time. The stochastic balance sheet deals with risk assessment, allowing policymakers and voters to recognize the probability at which the value of assets and liabilities will fluctuate over time as conditions change. They are gradually being applied to public sector balance sheets (Gapen and others, 2005; Barnhill and Kopits, 2003).

In principle, the complete stand-alone public sector balance sheet should be integrated into the sectoral balance sheet analysis of surveillance. This would bring out connections between important public and private actors in the economy, and between different economies, to highlight policy spillovers. For example, issues surrounding global imbalances can be illuminated with public balance sheet analysis because some countries are reacting relatively early to aging, thereby boosting their domestic savings, whereas others have hardly started, tending to lower savings. When some countries bolster their net savings to anticipate aging, while others do not, global imbalances will emerge. Publishing even preliminary balance sheets as part of the annual budget document would help bring them into the policy discussions.


References:

Allen, Mark, Brett House, and Christoph Rosenberg, 2007, "World Economy Balance Sheet Approach/Effects," forthcoming in Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy.

Allen, Mark, Christoph Rosenberg, Christian Keller, Brad Setser, and Nouriel Roubini, 2002, "A Balance Sheet Approach to Financial Crises," IMF Working Paper No. 02/210 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Barnhill, Theodore M., and George Kopits, 2003, Assessing Fiscal Sustainability under Uncertainty: Application of the Value-at-Risk Approach" (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Da Costa, Mercedes, and V. Hugo Juan-Ramon, 2006, "The Net Worth Approach to Fiscal Analysis: Dynamics and Rules," IMF Working Paper No. 06/17 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Gapen, Michael T., Dale Gray, Cheng Hoon Lim, and Yingbin Xiao, 2005, "Measuring and Analyzing Sovereign Risks with Contingent Claims," IMF Working Paper No. 05/155 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

International Monetary Fund, 2001, Government Finance Statistics Manual (Washington).

———, 2005, Using the GFSM 2001 Statistical Framework to Strengthen Fiscal Analysis in the Fund (Washington).

Kraemer, Moritz, John Chambers, and Beatriz Merino, 2005, "In the Long Run, We Are All Debt: Aging Societies and Sovereign Ratings," S&P Research Note, March 18.

Rosenberg, Christoph, Ioannis Haliakis, Brett House, Christian Keller, Jens Nystedt, Alexander Pitt, and Brad Setser, 2005, Debt Related Vulnerabilities and Financial Crises. An Application of the Balance Sheet Approach to Emerging Market Countries, IMF Occasional Paper No. 240 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).




Bob Traa is a Division Chief and Alina Carare an Economist in the IMF's European Department.