Sovereign Assets and Liabilities
Management

Ordering Information



Sovereign Assets and Liabilities Management
Editors: Marcel Cassard and David Folkerts-Landau

©2000 International Monetary Fund

 
Contents
Acknowledgments
1  Introduction
Marcel Cassard
2  Management of Sovereign Assets and Liabilities
Marcel Cassard and David Folkerts-Landau
3  Debt and Asset Management and Financial Crises: Sellers Beware
Michael P. Dooley

Comments by Philippe Jorion

4  Foreign Currency Liabilities in Debt Management
Patrick de Fontenay and Philippe Jorion

Comments by Gregory Makoff

5  Sovereign Liability Management: An Irish Perspective
Paul Sullivan
6  Management of Risks in Foreign Currency Funding and Debt Management
Bengt Rådstam
7  Autonomous Sovereign Debt Management Experience
Graeme Wheeler
8  Public Debt Management Strategy: Belgium's Experience
Louis de Montpellier
9  Central Bank Reserves Management
John Nugée
10  Trends in Central Bank Reserves Management
Jean-François Rigaudy
11  Reserves Management Operations in Australia
Rick Battellino
12  Foreign Borrowing by the Kingdom of Denmark
Ib Hansen
13  Credit Costs and Borrowing Capacity in Debt Optimization
Alejandro M. Pilato
14  Risk Management Process for Central Banks
Thomas E. Klaffky, Francis D. Glenister, and
Judith B. Otterman
15  Technical and Quantitative Aspects of Risk Management
Erol Hakanoglu
Notes on Contributors

 

Introduction
Marcel Cassard

The papers contained in this volume were presented at a conference entitled "Sovereign Assets and Liabilities Management" hosted by the International Monetary Fund and the Hong Kong Monetary Authority in Hong Kong SAR in November 1996. The conference focused on a wide range of issues confronting policymakers in managing their sovereign assets and liabilities in a world of mobile capital flows and integrated capital markets. The papers draw on the experiences of policymakers and private sector participants that have been actively involved in formulating and implementing debt and reserves policy. The policy choices are discussed against the background of alternative theoretical frameworks that are presented by a number of academics.

In the first paper, Cassard and Folkerts-Landau focus on the design of an institutional framework that enables a sound risk management of sovereign assets and liabilities and that reduces the vulnerability of sovereign portfolios to the volatility of international capital markets. The paper recommends the assignment of sovereign debt management to a separate debt agency with a large degree of autonomy from political influence. In particular, the authors propose that the sovereign authority communicate its debt strategy and policy constraints to the debt agency in the form of a benchmark portfolio, specifying the currency composition, maturity structure, and permissible instruments of the portfolio. An analytical framework that can be used to derive a benchmark and test its robustness is then discussed. The paper stresses that public disclosure of the reserve portfolio and benchmark as well as the performance of portfolio managers are key to achieving sound reserve management practices.

In the second paper, Dooley advocates a conservative debt management strategy, arguing that governments should limit their issuance of debt to homogeneous long-term domestic currency instruments. His argument is based on the premise that the main consideration in structuring sovereign asset and liability management is to avoid default. The issuance of only a single class of debt is necessary to avoid an adverse selection problem for sovereign credits, while denominating public debt in domestic currency is needed to obviate the large changes in the foreign currency value of government revenues owing to changes in the real exchange rate. The other reason for shunning foreign currency debt is the governments' limited ability to generate foreign currency revenues.

In his comments on the paper, Jorion outlines alternative theoretical models of asset and liability management to that proposed by Dooley, each of which implies a different conclusion regarding debt management policy. For instance, he argues that governments should issue long-term domestic debt when real shocks are important, but when monetary shocks dominate, such strategy would not be optimal. In alternative situations, if the government's anti-inflation stance is not credible, the private sector may increase the price of debt if it expects the government to inflate its debt away. In these circumstances, issuing floating rate debt or foreign currency debt may be preferable from the sovereign's viewpoint.

Following on Dooley's paper, de Fontenay and Jorion provide a comprehensive survey of various approaches to sovereign debt management, focusing on the optimal size of foreign currency debt for a country (if any) and the optimal composition of sovereign debt. In contrast to Dooley, the authors reach the conclusion that the sole issuance of domestic currency debt is not necessarily the optimal strategy for the sovereign. Indeed, developing countries should diversify the currency composition of their external debt to reduce the risks associated with the impact of interest rate and exchange rate changes on their ability to meet their external debt obligations. They also argue that the issuance of foreign currency- denominated debt can give the government's anti-inflation program credibility as it provides a signal that the authorities will not attempt to reduce the value of their debt through inflation. Taking Australia as a case study, the authors demonstrate how modern portfolio theory can be applied to generate an optimal currency composition for the Australian portfolio that is consistent with the authorities' objectives as well as projections of market developments.

In his comments on the paper, Makoff points to the sensitivity of the results of the analytical framework chosen to the choice of inputs, that is, historical or projected risk/return parameters. He suggests that caution should be exercised in applying portfolio theory; that the conclusions should be tested under a wide range of assumptions; and that significant constraints should be imposed to guarantee sufficient diversification and to enforce consistency with other portfolio objectives.

The second part of the conference volume focuses on the experience of various countries in managing their sovereign assets and liabilities. Sullivan opens the discussion, outlining both the institutional approach to debt management in Ireland and the main objectives and constraints facing policymakers. In Ireland, the National Treasury Management Agency was established in 1990 in response to a rapidly growing and increasingly complex debt position. According to Sullivan, the National Treasury Management Agency's principal objectives are to manage the debt in such a way as to protect both short-term and longer-term liquidity; contain the level and volatility of annual fiscal debt-service costs; reduce the Exchequer's exposure to risk; and outperform a benchmark or shadow portfolio. To achieve the desired fixed/floating mix and the targeted maturity structure of its foreign currency liability portfolio, the National Treasury Management Agency uses actively derivative markets. In view of Ireland's debt dynamics and the decline in domestic interest rates over the past few years, the National Treasury Management Agency has reduced the foreign currency component of its sovereign debt, issuing primarily longer-term fixed rate domestic currency debt.

Rådstam highlights the approach of the Swedish National Debt Office to debt management. The Swedish National Debt Office's objective is to minimize the long-term cost of the foreign currency debt within the risk limits established by the Board of the Swedish National Debt Office. With a foreign currency debt portfolio of over $60 billion, the Swedish National Debt Office is one of the largest borrowers in international markets. The currency composition of the benchmark has been chosen to reflect the prevailing currency regime in Sweden. In terms of the fixed/floating split, half of the debt is at floating rates and the other half at fixed rates with maturities of one, three, five, seven, and ten years in equal proportions. While the aim of the Swedish National Debt Office's benchmark is to ensure an average outcome in terms of cost, the agency is allowed to take currency and interest rate positions relative to the benchmark within risk limits laid down by the board. Indeed, during the past five years, the active management of the foreign currency debt has resulted in savings of over SKr 11 billion.

Wheeler then examines New Zealand's experience and ongoing innovation with sovereign debt management. The New Zealand Debt Management Office's objective is "to identify a low risk portfolio of net liabilities consistent with the Government's aversion to risk. . . and to transact in an efficient manner to achieve and maintain that portfolio." Wheeler outlines ways in which New Zealand's implementation of debt policy has been upgraded over the years. In particular, he notes that New Zealand has reconfigured its debt portfolio to remove foreign currency exposures and achieve a longer duration of NZ-dollar debt, including inflation-indexed securities.

Against the background of trends in Belgian public indebtedness and the reform of Belgian capital markets in the early 1990s, de Montpellier discusses the development of the Belgian Treasury's methodology of establishing a debt portfolio structure. Such a structure is defined as one that best minimizes the financial cost of the public debt within acceptable risk levels, while taking account of the macroeconomic objectives of the policymaker (budgetary and monetary policies). Indeed, in addition to the financial risks (market risk, credit risk, and operational risk) that any market participant is subject to, the manager of public debt has to be aware of the "macroeconomic" risks facing the policymaker. De Montpellier argues in favor of managing public debt separately from foreign assets, as the cash flows on the asset side of the state's balance sheet are not as sensitive to financial variables as are those on the debt side.

The papers presented by both Nugée and Rigaudy review trends in central bank reserve management in recent years. Based on an adherence to the balance sheet approach, Nugée argues in favor of managing sovereign assets and liabilities jointly, even if this entails identifying a common objective that does not interfere with the separate objectives of the central bank and the Ministry of Finance. He argues that from a national perspective, risks inherent in holding foreign currency reserves are best managed when aggregated at the highest level possible. If risks are too disaggregated, then control is sacrificed and the accumulation of a large number of small risks can become an unacceptable large risk. Nugée points out that by focusing on net reserves or liabilities, the sovereign can direct its attention more effectively to the part of its balance sheet at risk.

Rigaudy also identifies a number of significant changes that have taken place with regard to the objectives and investment policies of central banks. He notes that although the size of foreign reserves has increased substantially, the currency composition of reserves has remained stable. He argues that despite a large literature on the optimal level of reserves, the size of reserves in most countries is a consequence of economic policy, particularly monetary policy, rather than an objective per se. However, while liquidity remains the central issue for foreign exchange management, return maximization has become a more important concern. Rigaudy also discusses a number of thorny issues in reserve management, such as the management of gold reserves, the increased mobility of capital, and the difficulties of managing market activities in public institutions.

The next two papers present a practical experience of Australia's and Denmark's reserve management approaches. Battellino describes Australia's reserve management process, highlighting that reserves are primarily held to fund foreign exchange intervention with the purpose of moderating movements in the exchange rate in times of volatility. To this end, the Australian benchmark includes the three major reserve currencies (the U.S. dollar, the deutsche mark, and the Japanese yen) in roughly equal proportions, as the yen and deutsche mark display a strong negative covariance with the Australian dollar, while the latter is closely linked to the U.S. dollar. Battellino notes that the central bank has chosen a benchmark duration of 30 months because once the duration moves out beyond two and a half years, the risks of negative returns increase substantially. While the investment committee of the central bank is given considerable discretion in managing the reserve portfolio, the performance of the portfolio is carefully monitored: the portfolio is marked to market daily and reported to the Governors quarterly and to the public annually.

In contrast to Australia, Hansen explains that the Kingdom of Denmark manages its foreign debt and foreign exchange reserves within a coordinated framework focusing on the net foreign debt. The net debt is managed via the setting of a benchmark portfolio consisting of assets or liabilities in U.S. dollars, ERM currencies, Japanese yen, sterling, and Swiss francs, the distribution of which is decided by the Ministry of Finance and the central bank on a quarterly basis. Interest rate risk is managed by ensuring that the sovereign foreign assets and liabilities have a short duration, so that neither the interest rate risk of the government or central bank nor the combined risk of the two institutions is affected significantly by government borrowing to finance currency intervention.

Pilato exposes the risks that arise when lower-credit sovereign borrowers swap out of debt issued in foreign currencies back in their domestic currency to eliminate market risk and take advantage of arbitrage opportunities. He argues that the use of swaps constrain the borrowing capacity of lower-credit sovereigns by utilizing their credit lines with banks and expose them to higher counterparty risk as they often have to deal with lower-credit swap counterparties. Pilato describes an approach to measure the "cost" of swap counterparty credit risk based on the most likely or expected exposure and funding spreads. To consider this issue, he derives a debt optimization framework that takes into account borrowing capacity risk in addition to the conventional measures of risk—cost and volatility of cost. The optimal solution derived by the model is shown to be different from that derived by the usual optimization framework.

The last part of the conference volume turns to a discussion of private sector experiences with sovereign asset and liability management. Klaffky, Glenister, and Otterman discuss risk management and its application to central banks. After identifying several types of risk—market risk, credit risk, liquidity risk, legal risk, and operations risk—that confront central bankers, the paper describes the quantification of portfolio market risk and the role of a benchmark in the investment strategy. The authors especially focus on how risk should be managed in an institutional setting, discussing the types of checks and balances that should be established to facilitate the monitoring and improvement of the risk management process.

In the final paper of the volume, Hakanoglu discusses the methodology used in the Goldman Sachs Asset-Liability Management Model to determine the optimal maturity profile and currency composition of a sovereign debt portfolio. Hakanoglu first highlights the simulations (Monte Carlo) used to construct an optimal portfolio, then discusses the various issues involved in measuring the risk tolerance of the client, and finally demonstrates the construction of an optimal portfolio to reflect such risk tolerance. The paper explains how a benchmark portfolio can be derived and stresses that a benchmark should represent a minimum risk position for the sovereign that takes into account various market exposures and the long-term objectives and constraints under which the sovereign is operating. Typically, a benchmark would approximate the desired long-term portfolio of the sovereign, and would be used to measure the performance of the actual sovereign portfolio.